Deconstructing the World Bank’s New Poverty and Inequality Numbers - Part 1
Part 1: The Recalibration of India: Deconstructing the World Bank’s New Poverty and Inequality Numbers
When the
World Bank releases a major update to its Poverty and Inequality Platform
(PIP), it’s a significant event for global development watchers. But when that
update involves India, a country home to one-sixth of humanity, the
implications are monumental. The "June 2025 Update" is just such an
event. At first glance, the numbers are startling, suggesting a dramatic and
rapid decline in both poverty and, most strikingly, inequality in India. It’s a
narrative that aligns with a story of broad-based progress. Yet, as I began to
delve into the accompanying technical note, a far more complex and layered
picture emerged. The story of India's improved metrics is not a simple tale of
policy triumph; it is an intricate interplay of genuine progress, profound methodological
shifts, and critical data omissions. This update is less a photograph of India
and more a recalibration of the camera itself. Understanding the nature of this
recalibration is the most important task for anyone seeking to grasp the
reality of poverty and inequality in India today.
The
significance of this update lies not just in the new numbers it presents, but
in the fundamental break it creates with all previously published data. To
comprehend the shift, we must first understand the machinery. The Gini index,
our primary metric for inequality, measures the distribution of a resource—in
this case, consumption—across a population. A score of 0 represents perfect
equality (everyone has the same), while a score of 100 represents perfect
inequality (one person has everything). For years, India’s Gini hovered in the
mid-to-high 30s, a figure that, while not extreme, pointed to significant
disparities. The new report, however, presents a Gini of just 28.8 for 2011,
plummeting to 25.5 by 2022. This is a seismic shift. To put it in
perspective, the previous World Bank vintage, published just months earlier in
September 2024, had reported a Gini of 35.4 for the very same year, 2011.
How can a country’s inequality metric for a year in the past fall by nearly 7
points overnight? The answer has nothing to do with history and everything to
do with methodology. The Bank has, in essence, re-engineered its entire
approach to measuring Indian consumption, and this re-engineering accounts for
the lion’s share of the “improvement.”
Let's
break down the four key factors driving this change.
-
The
single most dominant factor, which the report’s own analysis suggests accounts
for a staggering 80% of the reduction in inequality, is the shift in
the survey's recall period. Previously, India’s surveys used a Uniform
Reference Period (URP), asking households to recall all their expenditures over
the last 30 days. The new methodology, applied retroactively to 2011, uses a
Modified Mixed Reference Period (MMRP). Under MMRP, families report frequent
purchases like food and groceries over a short period (7 or 30 days) but recall
infrequent, lumpy expenditures like clothing, footwear, or small appliances
over a full year (365 days). The impact of this is profound. A low-income
family might not buy a new sari or a pair of school shoes every month, so a
30-day survey could easily miss this expenditure, understating their annual
consumption. A 365-day recall for these items captures this spending far more
accurately. This systematically lifts the measured consumption of lower and
middle-income households, who spend a larger portion of their non-food budget
on such lumpy items. It has a powerful compressive effect on the entire
distribution, closing the gap between the bottom and the top and, consequently,
causing the Gini index to fall dramatically.
-
The
second factor is the construction of a new welfare aggregate. This is
not one change but a collection of crucial adjustments that collectively lift
the bottom of the distribution while lowering the top. To lift the bottom, the
Bank now imputes a market-equivalent price for goods received through the
Public Distribution System (PDS). For decades, a poor family’s consumption was
valued at the one or two rupees they paid for subsidized grain, or zero if it
was free. This was a massive understatement of their real welfare. By valuing
that 35kg of grain at its market price, the new methodology correctly captures
the enormous impact of India’s food security net, boosting the measured welfare
of millions. Simultaneously, the methodology lowers the top by excluding
certain types of expenditure. Purchases of durable goods, jewelry, and even
wristwatches are no longer counted. The justification is that these are often
stores of value, not pure consumption. Furthermore, and critically, the value
of housing services has been completely excluded for both renters and
homeowners due to challenges in consistent data capture. Since wealthier, urban
households spend disproportionately more on high-value items and housing,
excluding these components clips the top of the consumption distribution, further
compressing the Gini index.
-
The
third and fourth factors, the revision of price deflators and the adoption
of new 2021 Purchasing Power Parities (PPPs), are more technical but
important. Using more granular state-specific price indices instead of simple
urban-rural ones makes the data far more accurate in a country as diverse as
India. However, its impact on the Gini index is minimal compared to the MMRP
and welfare aggregate changes. The new PPPs, meanwhile, primarily affect the
international poverty headcount—for instance, changing the extreme poverty line
from $2.15 to $3.00 per day. They have no direct impact on the Gini index,
which is calculated on the domestic currency distribution before any
international conversion. Together, these four changes create the
"structural break." The India of 2011 in this report is a
statistically different entity from the India of 2011 in all previous reports.
The fall in inequality from 35.4 to 28.8 for that year is not a reflection of a
newly discovered reality, but the result of applying a new measurement ruler.
The subsequent, more modest decline from 28.8 in 2011 to 25.5 in 2022 is the
trend we are now invited to analyze, a trend that is itself shaped by these new
methodological choices.
What
this new, re-engineered camera fails to capture, however, is as important as
what it now brings into focus. The report, based on the Household Consumption
Expenditure Survey (HCES), is silent on the crucial questions of income and
wealth. It tells us what households spend, but not how they earn.
There are no metrics here on access to better jobs, rising wages, or
entrepreneurial income. Has inequality of opportunity in the labor
market improved? We cannot say from this data. The improved consumption at the
bottom could be from better wages, or it could be, as the methodology itself
suggests, overwhelmingly from government transfers. The report shows a
population that is better supported, but not necessarily one that is more
empowered through income generation. The omission of wealth is even more stark.
The methodology explicitly excludes the primary channels of wealth creation and
accumulation for ordinary families: the purchase of durables, the value of
housing, and other assets. In a period where India has seen a booming stock
market and significant real estate activity, this is a colossal blind spot. We
are being shown a picture of declining consumption inequality while being left
completely in the dark about what might be a very different, and potentially
diverging, trend in wealth inequality. The report cannot tell us if the bottom
40% are accumulating assets or falling further behind in the race for wealth.
In conclusion, the World Bank’s June 2025 update is a landmark revision that must be handled with extreme care. The good is that the new methodology is undeniably more robust. It is far better at capturing the real-world impact of India’s massive social safety net, particularly the PDS, providing a more accurate measure of the consumption floor in the country. This is a welcome and long-overdue improvement. The bad, however, is the high potential for misinterpretation. The headline-grabbing drop in the Gini index is primarily a statistical artifact of this methodological change, not a simple continuation of a past trend. Comparing the new Gini of 25.5 to the old figures in the mid-30s is a comparison of apples and oranges. The most significant shortcoming, however, lies in its omissions. By focusing exclusively on a narrow definition of consumption and actively excluding proxies for wealth, the report presents a partial and potentially sanitised view of inequality. For policymakers, this is perilous. It risks fostering complacency by highlighting success in consumption support while masking potential failures in promoting equitable income opportunities and preventing the concentration of wealth. The public, in turn, may be led to believe that the challenge of inequality is far smaller than it actually is. This update has given us a better tool to measure one part of the elephant, but we must not forget that it leaves the other, perhaps larger, parts entirely in the dark.
Comments
Post a Comment